While there is agreement among economists and health care experts that overall the US has highly inflationary health care expenses over the long term - certainly compared to other relatively wealthy countries with high-quality medical care and much better health outcomes - Uwe E. Reinhardt
@ New York Times Economix shows, once again, that the locus of this "out of control" spending isn't Medicare:
It’s the season of holiday cocktail parties, demanding intelligent
chit-chat over Chardonnay. In such data-free environments it is always
safe to say, “Medicare spending is out of control!” Wise heads will nod,
because it is a credo with wide currency.
After all, as I explained in my previous post,
traditional Medicare, which still attracts about 75 percent of all
Medicare beneficiaries, affords its enrollees free choice of providers
and therapy. In the jargon of health-policy wonks, it is “unmanaged.”
Thus, it would not be surprising if unmanaged Medicare spending were,
indeed, out of control.
But some caution is in order. A really
wise guy in the crowd, one familiar with relevant data, might challenge
you with: “Oh, really? In what sense is Medicare spending out of
control?”
That query might have been prompted by the following data.
Kaiser Family Foundation
These data, most of which have been published
by the Office of the Actuary, Centers of Medicare and Medicaid
Services, of the Department of Health and Human Services (see Table 16),
show that in most periods Medicare spending per Medicare beneficiary
has risen more slowly than per-capita spending under private health
insurance.
The exceptions are the period 1993-97, when private
managed-care plans appeared to be able to hold down their outlays on
health care better than did Medicare, and 2002-7, because there was a
jump in spending as Medicare began, in 2006, to cover prescription drugs under the Medicare Prescription Drug, Improvement and Modernization Act of 2003.
So
anyone claiming that “Medicare spending is out of control” can fairly
be asked to explain on what data that assertion is based. The responses
might be interesting.
Two objections might be raised to my interpretation of the data.
First,
the benefit package of Medicare differs from those of private health
insurers at any point in time. Worse still, benefit packages have varied
over time in both sectors. This makes such comparisons difficult.
During
the 1990s, for example, when Medicare’s benefit package remained
relatively stable, those in employment-based private insurance expanded
significantly, especially in their coverage of prescription drugs, which
soon became the fastest-growing component of health spending among
private insurers. In those years, Medicare did not cover prescription
drugs.
Similarly, during the last decade or so, many private
health-insurance policies have incorporated more and more cost-sharing
by patients at point of service.
To control as best they can for
differences in benefit packages, the centers’ actuaries also calculate
comparative growth rates over longer periods of time for only those
benefits that have been covered by both Medicare and private insurance
plans. The two right-most columns in the exhibit present those
calculations.
These columns, too, hardly support the assertion
that Medicare spending is out of control. Relative to private insurance,
the opposite appears to be the case, with the exceptions noted above.
A second objection to my interpretation of the data might be that Medicare is what economists call a “monopsonist,”
a single buyer in a market with many sellers. In such a market, the
monopsonistic buyer has considerable power over the level and the growth
rate of prices over time.
With very few exceptions, Medicare pays
prices to providers of health care below those paid by private
insurers, which individually negotiate prices with each provider. I have
already described Medicare’s pricing practices in several earlier posts and pricing practices in the private insurance market as well.
Critics of Medicare — notably private health insurers — contend that the higher prices for health care paid by private insurers can be explained by a “cost shift” from government, notably Medicare, to private payers. This view reflects the idea
that the providers of health care are to be “reimbursed” for whatever
costs they incur in treating patients, rather than budgeting backward
from whatever revenue they are “paid,” like other sellers (e.g., hotels
or airlines), which can charge different prices to different customers
for the same thing.
The cost-shift hypothesis appears to have
widespread, intuitive appeal, especially among employers and their
agents, private insurers. Economists, this one included, do not find it persuasive, as can be seen in this review of the economics literature on the cost-shift hypothesis and this summary.
Economists believe that what is denounced as “cost shifting” in health
care is mainly just good old-fashioned, profit-maximizing price
discrimination based on differential market power, which is not to be
confused with cost shifting.
The economists’ skepticism aside, I
would caution the proponents of the cost-shift hypothesis to think twice
before injecting it into the health policy debate...
With social media, the groups that an aspiring healthcare professional joins have changed. Sure, there are still some of the old groups used in previous generations, which can be used. Social media provides more options. del taco low carb
ReplyDelete