The potential dangers of financial instruments, they argue, “seem at least as extreme as the dangers of medicines.”
They contend that new instruments should be approved by a “financial
products agency” that would test them for social utility. Ideally,
products deemed too costly to society over all — those that serve only
to increase speculation, for example — would be rejected, the two
professors say...
It is a refreshing rejoinder to the mantra on Wall Street — and in some
circles in Washington — that financial innovation is always good and
regulation is always bad. Bankers often argue that complex financial
products are among America’s great inventions.
But given that exotic instruments played a central role in the credit
crisis, it is worth questioning the costs and benefits of such financial
innovations. The paper by Mr. Posner and Mr. Weyl provides a basis for
what could be a productive dialogue.
“We tried an experiment with a very radical form of deregulation that
has very little basis in sound economic science,” Mr. Weyl said in an
interview last week. “What we’re advocating is to do the best we can to
put the genie back in the bottle.”
FIRST, their paper says, we should distinguish between financial markets
— where institutions lend money, trade securities and make investments —
and the real economy, where people trade goods and services.
“It is tempting to think that if the real economy should be largely
unregulated (as it is), then the financial markets should be as well,”
the professors wrote. But that view, they went on, is wrong.
Instead, they advocate testing new financial products for social
benefits. For example, financial instruments could be judged by whether
they help people hedge risks — which is generally beneficial — or
whether they simply allow gambling, which can be costly.
The instruments could also be measured for how they affect capital
allocation, and whether they might add useful information to the
marketplace.
The professors note certain instruments that they say have added little to society. Among them are
credit default swaps, which were devised in the 1990s and became enormously popular.
The paper concludes that credit default swaps have considerable
drawbacks. Those who use swaps to hedge their debt holdings, for
example, assume the risks of dealing with counterparties. Swaps also
contribute little to the appropriate allocation of capital, the
professors say, because investors use them to take positions on debt
that is already outstanding. And the paper dismisses the notion that
such swaps provide significant information to the market about the
safety of underlying debt.
Imagining a credit default swap being brought before a financial
protection agency, Mr. Posner and Mr. Weyl wrote: “We would expect the
F.P.A. to treat it skeptically.” ...
The professors also question the central tenet of the nation’s financial
regulatory framework — that full disclosure provides enough protection
for investors.
“My major concern about Dodd-Frank is that the basic philosophy behind
it is to improve disclosure, the traditional way of addressing market
failures in a way that is thought to be helpful but not too intrusive,”
Mr. Posner said last week.
But disclosure alone isn’t enough in the pharmaceutical industry, he
said, and the same view should be applied to finance.
“In pharmaceuticals, we could allow a company to sell whatever it wants
as long as it tells people the product might work but also might cause
your head to fall off,” Mr. Posner said. “We don’t do that because
people will ignore the information, so we draw the line and say, ‘You
can’t buy that product.’ ” ...
THE proposal by Mr. Posner and Mr. Weyl is unlikely to get off the
ground anytime soon. But if their ideas open a discussion about
measuring the social costs of our financial products, that alone would
be a step forward.
No comments:
Post a Comment